Image: But can your social welfare spending buy this?!?!? (Northern lights over Saurbaer, Iceland / flickr user
benhusmann)
I'm revisiting
this 2014 post for two reasons. First--and most importantly--I did not realize when I first wrote it how important it was, so I outlined general trends and was not super careful about my analysis. My aim was to point out the hypocrisy of crying foul at the high tax rates of the social democracies even though a typical American is far worse off due to the high cost of private social welfare services. 40% taxes may seem high, but a median income American family can expect to spend over 60% of their income on federal (income plus payroll) taxes, employer-sponsored health insurance, and recommended savings for retirement
alone--and this doesn't even include student loans payments (an additional 11% of income on an income-based repayment plan), day care services (up to 30% of income depending on the state), or other common social welfare costs. You don't need super careful analysis to make this point.
Second, some OECD links I used are now broken and so it's no longer clear where the data are coming from.
I'm keeping the original post up because it has some research which I don't need to repeat. But here, I'm going to be less sloppy on my analysis of labor costs and social welfare contributions.
You can read this page alone and consult the original post for links that didn't make it into this post. Before beginning, recall that median income in the United States is
pretty similar to the social democracies. Here is the revised table for median income households (click for unobscured image):
The blue percentages at the top of the table are expressed as a percentage of gross labor costs. For the American side, this means:
At first, it might seem reasonable to consider at what a typical family
earns in income, then consider what percentage of that income they pay in
taxes and for social welfare. But this is misleading, for two major reasons. I call this the "sticker price" of the social welfare state--the cost of the social welfare state
that a typical individual or family sees, but
not the cost that they actually pay.
The first reason why the sticker price is misleading is because it comes nowhere near the total cost of the welfare state for this family. The sticker price ignores many costs that support this family's social welfare benefits and services: the cost of employer contributions to
Social Security, Medicare, and employer-sponsored health
insurance, for example. Since these are costs that support the social
welfare needs of this family, it makes no sense to ignore them.
Second, it simply makes no sense to think of individual labor costs as somehow different from each other. It makes no difference to an employer--whether American or
Scandinavian--if a dollar is spent on cash wages, mandatory social security
contributions, or fringe benefits; to an employer, a dollar
spent on labor costs is a dollar spent on labor costs, no matter the
final destination of that dollar. Indeed, in the social democracies,
90% of social security tax burden
falls on workers; in other words, for every dollar an employer is
forced to contribute to social security programs, a worker's wage falls
90 cents. Thus--on paper--employers pay 100% of the employer
contribution to social security, but in reality, employees pay for
nearly all of those contributions because their wages would be higher if
the employer's social security taxes did not exist. And in the United States, a
similar phenomenon occurs with employer-sponsored health insurance: employees accept lower wages at jobs that offer health insurance. Clearly, looking at one form of labor costs (cash wages) while ignoring all the others makes no sense since the line between wages, benefits, and mandatory employer social security contributions is blurred, to say the least.
In sum, it makes no sense to point to the sticker price as being a complete accounting of the social welfare costs of a typical family; it ignores too many costs of the social welfare state and ignores several forms of labor costs.
Thus, the only
way to fairly estimate the total cost of the welfare state is to sum
every component of welfare spending and express it as a percentage of
every dollar spent on labor costs--and so I've done this for both the
American and social democratic columns (the blue percentages at the top of the first table). This is captured for the American side in the immediately preceding table (the social democratic side is covered below), which is a complete accounting of the cost of the welfare state to a median income American family. The
left column is every dollar that this family's employers spend on them:
this includes wages, benefits, and mandatory contributions to
Social Security. On the right is every
dollar that goes to taxes or social welfare: all taxes and social security contributions paid by both
employer and employee on wages or labor, and all money spent on social welfare benefits
paid by both
employer and employee (discussed in greater detail below). Obviously, some items are in both columns--for example, employer contributions to health insurance and employer contributions to Social Security are both labor costs to the employer
and are social welfare costs. This table is the total cost of the welfare state for
this median-income individual family: all taxes, social security
contributions, and spending on private social welfare benefits as a
percentage of every dollar an employer must spend to employ this family.
Here is a table of the cost of other common social welfare benefits and services, alongside their out-of-pocket cost in the American social welfare system--in dollars, as a percentage of income for a median income family, and as a percentage of gross labor costs for a median income family:
There is a range for child care because the cost of high quality
child care services varies wildly by state. In nearly all states,
however, annual child care costs exceed the cost of tuition at a public
university.
The above three tables
is this blog post. Before proceeding, please
return to the three above tables. Clearly, the American social welfare system is a phenomenally bad deal for a typical family compared to the social democratic model.
Here's the outline for the rest of this post:
- As bad as the American side looks in these tables, it's actually worse than these basic numbers suggest. This is because the American side forces individual households to bear enormous risks in health care, retirement, and long term care. Also, the social welfare services available to a median income American family are of far lower quality than those same social welfare services available to a median income family in the social democracies. If we only look at the raw numbers, we lose sight of enormous financial risk and poor service quality of the American social welfare system.
- The research or calculations behind each cell of all three of the above tables.
The horrors of the American long term care system
Long term care refers to health care equipment or services for patients who are grievously injured or very, very sick. These patients will never get better; they will be sick or badly injured until they die, and they will likely die from their injury or illness.